111 510 510 libonline@riphah.edu.pk Contact

Anchoring KP province

I learnt there is just one flight per week from Lahore to Peshawar and it returns three days later. This prompted an investigation of how Peshawar is connected to the outside world.

Here is some quick information on the flights per week to Peshawar and their origins: none from Central Asia; one from East Asia; one from Afghanistan: one from Punjab; two from Balochistan; four from within Khyber Pakhtunkhwa; four from Islamabad; 10 from Sindh; and 56 from the Middle East.

While KP is part of Pakistan, it seems reasonable to infer that its economic engine is in the Middle East. One might post oneself outside Peshawar airport to determine the nature of the economic engine. I doubt one would see investors armed with briefcases and laptops. Much more like-ly that the vast majority would comprise migrant workers returning home for a break with the type of consumer goods that unskilled and semiskilled migrant workers come back with.

This would confirmthat KP is a manpower exporting economy. It does not generate enough jobs to employ its labour force; nor does the rest of Pakistan put together. The type of work for which the human capital of KP has been equipped by its governments is to be found in sufficient numbers in Karachi and, at a living wage, mostly in the Middle East.

This is not an outcome of the recent unrest in the province. It has been so for a long time. I wrote a paper in 1992 The Spatial Pattern of International Labour Flows from and to Pakistan which showed that the NWFP (as it was then called) was the province with the highest relative outmigration from Pakistan (about three times the national average) and the lowest return migration to Pakistan (about half the national average). There was little for people to do in the province and little for them to come back to.

Within the NWFP, Peshawar district had the highest relative outmigration (over six times the national average)and the lowest return migration (about a fifth of the national average) suggesting that better prepared workers were even more likely to leave the province and even less likely to return.

Clearly the prospects for socioeconomic development would be dented if those most likely to contribute were left with no alternative but to exit.

It might be argued that there is nothing really problematic with the above scenario we are part of a global economy and labour moves to where the jobs are. There are many sociological and political reasons to argue to the contrary.

Think of the inner cities in the US that were reduced to pockets of poverty after the flight of the affluent to the suburbs. The pathologies that arise from such phenomena are a source of concern to social scientists. One could surmise that the rise of social and religious conservatism in KP is an outcome of its manpower-exporting economy, anchored in the Middle East, which transforms labourers into small-property owners imbued with the values of its host society.
For an economist, the aspect of interest is not that labour moves to where the jobs are but why jobs are not in KP. Is it a desert capable of growing or producing nothing? Since few would subscribe to that judgement a search is needed for a plausible explanation.

The corollary to the above is that there has been very little investment in KP from neighbouring Punjab or from Karachi, despite the fact that the province is rich in energy potential and many kinds of natural resources.

At the very least one might have expected over the many preceding decades some relocation of industry attracted by lower land and labour costs in KP. An examination of the reasons for the absence might be a good place to start in designing a new development strategy for the province.

A thought experiment might trigger some ideas. Imagine KP as an independent country no longer eligible for alloca-tions from a federal budget. What might it do to generate its own revenues and how might it go about attracting foreign direct investment from its neighbouring countries? One could add an analogy to the thought experiment. There was a time when Mexico was exporting its labour across the border to the US for agricultural work. The shock of suspension of the arrangement in 1965 was the catalyst for a border industrialisation programme designed to provide alternative employment.

By the end of the century, almost 4,000 factories financed by US investment were generating 25pc of Mexico`s GDP, almost 50pc of its exports, and about 10pc of its formal employment.

The analogy might seem far-fetched but is suggestive of a vision to develop the province. Central to the vision is identifying the type of industry compatible with the province`s natural resource endowments, the type of infrastructureand skills required to operate the industries, the type of incentives needed to attract back skilled labour, and the downstream industries that would cater to the consumption needs of workers with risingincomes to keep money circulating in the domestic economy.

In thinking of a border industrialisation programme it might be useful to reexamine the experience of the Hattar Industrial Estate located on the PunjabNWFP border presumably to attract capital investment.
By all accounts it has not been a success a recent report indicated that abandoned and sick industrial units exceeded in number those that were operational and under construction. The reasons remain to be fully examined.

Khyber Pakhtunkhwa is a rich province poorly served by its governments. Its citizens deserve better. They are too desperate to leave and too much in debt to find the time or energy to protest but such good fortune may not last forever. • The writer is dean of the School of Humanities, Social Sciences and Law at the Lahore University of Management Sciences.

Anjum Altaf, "Anchoring KP province," Dawn. 2013-06-30.
Keywords: Social sciences , Economics , Economical issues , Labour force , Socia development , Investment , Balochistan , Khyber Pakhtunkhwa , Peshawar , NWFP , GDP